每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

蓝·灯下载

 

A number of New Researchers who had been due to present their work at the 2024 EHS Annual Conference will soon be discussing their research in a series of online sessions.

 

Some of these New Researchers have also agreed to share some of their research in the form of blog posts and videos, which will be made available prior to each online session. All available materials will be linked below.

 

Please note that these online sessions are not a replacement for the EHS Annual Conference, and new researchers are made up of postgraduates and early career researchers.

 

Sessions will be held every Wednesday, between 15th July and 19th August.

 

These sessions will last no longer than 1 hour and 15 minutes, with time for questions and discussion at the end. Presenters are appearing from across the world, and times have been chosen to best accommodate this.

 

We welcome and encourage attendance from anyone interested in economic and social history. All sessions are available for members and non-members of the EHS.

 

The following sessions are available, all GMT+1 (current London time):

 

  • Finance, Currency & Crisis – 15th July @ 4:30pm
    • Ruben Peeters (Utrecht University) – ‘Solving the perennial small firm credit problem: The case of the Netherlands, 1900-1940’
    • Maylis Avaro (Graduate Institute, Geneva & University Libre de Bruxelles) – ‘Zombie International Currency: The Pound Sterling 1945-1973’
    • Ryan Smith (University of Glasgow) – ‘The Middle East and the 1982 debt crisis’

 

  • Lantern官方网站 – 22nd July @ 10am
    • Mostafa Abdelaal (University of Cambridge) – ‘Elusive promises: The impacts of the Central African Federation on industrial development in Northern Rhodesia, 1953-63’
    • Björn Brey (University of Nottingham) – ‘The long-run gains from the early adoption of electricity’
    • Alexander Urrego-Mesa (Universitat de Barcelona) – ‘Food Security, Trade and Violence: From the First to the Second Globalization in Colombia 1916-2016’

 

  • Human Capital & Development – 29th July @ 5pm
    • Kathryne Crossley (University of Oxford) – ‘Honest, sober and willing: Oxford college servants, 1850-1939’
    • Matthew Curtis (University of California, Davis) – ‘The quantity and quality of pre-industrial children: Evidence from Québécois twins’

 

  • Equality & Wages – 5th August @ 9am
    • Tamer Güven (Istanbul University) – ‘Wages in the Ottoman textile factories, 1848-99’
    • Theresa Neef (Freie Universität Berlin) – ‘The long way to gender equality: Gender differences in pay in Germany, 1871-2016’
    • Yuzuru Kumon (Bocconi University) – ‘The deep roots of inequality’

 

  • Government & Colonization – 12th August @ 3pm
    • 蓝奏·云存储:在蓝奏,所有云存储、文件下载都是秒级响应。采用网众公司云计算+存储分发技术。任何网络,享受到最快的下载速度。
    • 蓝灯百度网盘资源下载 百度网盘 百度云 微盘 新浪微盘_如风搜:2021-1-8 · 蓝灯相关的网盘资源搜索,包括百度网盘资源和微盘资源等 最近收录 如风搜 42.96ms 建议反馈 帮助中心 免责声明 用户协议 投诉或建议请来邮: rufengso@yandex.com 手机版 如搜索结果侵犯了您的相关权益请来邮通知,本站将根据相关法律规定 ...

 

  • Spending & Networks – 19th August @ 12pm
    • Xabier García Fuente (Universitat de Barcelona) – ‘The paradox of redistribution in time: Social spending in 48 countries, 1967-2016’
    • Andres Mesa (Università degli Studi di Teramo) – ‘The Diaspora of a Diaspora: The Cassana and Rivarolo family network in the Atlantic, 1450-1530’

 

More information on how to attend 灯蓝app下载

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

Inspired by the curated series available here, we are creating a collective bibliography on Pandemics in History to help us navigating the “uncharted territory” that we are currently living – it includes references from academic papers, book, and journals, as well as a section on primary resources in collaboration with Archives Portal Europe. Everyone is welcome to join & contribute: just add your references to the shared file, according to the existing categories, or create new categories if needed

http://docs.google.com/document/d/1up4Kgm9aFAGyLy3E-rUmw5xvzUxMRDGtdOxE0LKjDu0/edit?usp=sharing

pandemic_promo-gettyimages-487955477

 

 

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

By Pei Gao (NYU Shanghai) & Eric B. Schneider (LSE)

The full article from this blog is forthcoming in the Economic History Review and is currently available on Early View.

 

Gao4
HMS Indefatigable with HMS Diadem (1898) in the Gulf of St. Lawrence 1901. Available at Wikimedia Commons.

Since the mid-nineteenth century, the average height of adult British men increased by 11 centimetres. This increase in final height reflects improvements in living standards and health, and provides insights on the growth pattern of children which has been comparatively neglected. Child growth is very sensitive to economic and social conditions: children with limited nutrition or who suffer from chronic disease, grow more slowly than healthy children. Thus, to achieve such a large increase in adult height, health conditions must have improved dramatically for children since the mid-nineteenth century.

Our paper seeks to understand how child growth changed over time as adult height was increasing. Child growth follows a typical pattern shown in Figure 1.  The graph on the left shows the height by age curve for modern healthy children, and the graph on the right shows the change in height at each age (height velocity). We look at three dimensions of the growth pattern of children: the final adult height that children achieve, i.e. what historians have predominantly focused on to date; the timing (age) when the growth velocity peaks during puberty,  and, finally,   the overall speed of maturation which affects the velocity of growth across all ages and the length of the growing years.

 

Figure 1.         Weights and Heights for boys who trained on HMS Indefatigable, 1860s-1990s.

Gao1
Source: as per article

 

To understand how growth changed over time, we collected information about 11,548 boys who were admitted to the training ship Indefatigable from the 1860s to 1990s (Figure 2).  This ship was located on the River Mersey near Liverpool for much of its history and it trained boys for careers in the merchant marine and navy. Crucially, the administrators recorded the boys’ heights and weights at admission and discharge, allowing us to calculate growth velocities for each individual.

 

Figure 2.         HMS Indefatigable

Gao2
Source: By permission, the Indefatigable Old Boys Society

 

We trace the boys’ heights over time (grouping them by birth decade) and find that they grew most rapidly during the interwar period. In addition, the most novel finding was that for boys born in the nineteenth century there is little evidence that they experienced a strong pubertal growth spurt unlike healthy boys today. Their growth velocity was relatively flat across puberty.  However, starting with the 1910 birth decade, boys began experiencing more rapid pubertal growth similar to the right-hand graph in Figure 1. The appearance of rapid pubertal growth is a product of two factors: an increase in the speed of maturation, which meant that boys grew more rapidly during puberty than before and, secondly,  a decrease in the variation in the timing of the pubertal growth spurt, which meant that boys were experiencing their pubertal growth at more similar ages.

 

Figure 3.         Adjusted height-velocity for boys who trained on HMS Indefatigable.

latern专业破解版安卓最新版
Source: as per article

 

This sudden change in the growth pattern of children is a new finding that is not predicted by the historical or medical literature.  In the paper, we show that this change cannot be explained by improvements in living standards on the ship and that it is robust to a number of potential alternative explanations.   We argue that reductions in disease exposure and illness were likely the biggest contributing factor. Infant mortality rates, an indicator of chronic illness in childhood, declined only after 1900 in England and Wales, so a decline in illness in childhood could have mattered. In addition, although general levels of nutrition were more than adequate by the turn of the twentieth century, the introduction of free school meals and the milk-in-schools programme in the early twentieth century,  likely also helped ensure that children had access to key protein and nutrients necessary for growth.

Our findings matter for two reasons. First, they help complete the fragmented picture in the existing historical literature on how children’s growth changed over time. Second, they highlight the importance of the 1910s and the interwar period as a turning point in child growth. Existing research on adult heights has already shown that the interwar period was a period of rapid growth for children, but our results further explain how and why child growth accelerated in that period.

 


Pei Gao

p.gao@nyu.edu

 

Eric B. Schneider

e.b.schneider@lse.ac.uk

Twitter: @ericbschneider

 

 

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

By Ulas Karakoc (TOBB ETU, Ankara & Humboldt University Berlin) & Laura Panza (University of Melbourne)

The full article from this blog is forthcoming in the Economic History Review.

 

Panza1
A study of diversity in Egyptian cotton, 1909. Available at Wikimedia Commons.

By 1914, Egypt’s large agricultural sector was negatively hit by declining yields in cotton production. Egypt at the time was a textbook case of export-led development.  The decline in cotton yields — the ‘cotton crisis’ — was coupled with two other constraints: land scarcity and high population density. Nonethless, Egyptian agriculture was able to overcome this crisis in the interwar period, despite unfavourable price shocks. The output stagnation between 1900 and the 1920s clearly contrasts with the following recovery (Figure 1). In this paper, we empirically examine how this happened, by focusing on the role of government investment in irrigation infrastructure, farmers crop choices (intra-cotton shifts), and access to credit.

 

Figure 1: Cotton output, acreage and yields, 1895-1940

Panza2
Source: Annuaire Statistique (various issues)

 

The decline in yields was caused by expanded irrigation without sufficient drainage, leading to a higher water table, increased salination, and increased pest attacks on cotton (Radwan, 1974; Owen, 1968; Richards, 1982).  The government introduced an extensive public works programme, to reverse soil degradation and restore production. Simultaneously, Egypt’s farmers changed the type of cotton they were cultivating, shifting from the long staple and low yielding Sakellaridis to the medium-short staple and high yielding 灯蓝app下载, which reflected income maximizing preferences (Goldberg 2004 and 2006). Another important feature of the Egyptian economy between the 1920s and 1940s, was the expansion of credit facilities and the connected increase in farmers’ accessibility to agricultural loans. The interwar years witnessed the establishment of cooperatives to facilitate small landowners’ access to inputs (Issawi,1954), and the foundation of the Crèdit Agricole in 1931, offering small loans (Eshag and Kamal, 1967). These credit institutions coexisted with a number of mortgage banks, among which the Credit Foncièr was the largest, servicing predominantly large owners. Figure 2 illustrates the average annual real value of Credit Foncièr land mortgages in 1,000 Egyptian pounds (1926-1939).

 

Figure 2: Average annual real value of Credit Foncièr land mortgages in 1,000 Egyptian pounds (1926-1939)

Panza3
Source: Annuaire Statistique (various issues)

 

Our work investigates the extent to which these factors contributed to the recovery of the raw cotton industry. Specifically: to what extent can intra-cotton shifts explain changes in total output? How did the increase in public works, mainly investment in the canal and drainage network, help boost production? And what role did differential access to credit play? To answer these questions, we construct a new dataset by exploiting official statistics (《三十而已百度云》网盘资源(全1-35集)【1080P蓝光中字 ...:护宝计中计百度云[HD1080p资源][百度云盘链接下载] 《99分女朋友百度云》网盘资源(全1-16集)【1080P蓝光中字】泄露版资源已更新 纪录片《在武汉》百度云(手机版)网盘完结版【1080P中字】无删减资 …) covering 11 provinces and 17 years during 1923-1939. These data allow us to provide the first empirical estimates of Egyptian cotton output at the province level.

Access to finance and improved seeds significantly increased cotton output. The declining price premium of Sakellaridis led to a large-scale switch to 蓝·灯下载, which indicates that farmers responded to market incentives in their cultivation choices. Our study shows that cultivators’ response to market changes was fundamental in the recovery of the cotton sector. Access to credit was also a strong determinant of cotton output, especially to the benefit of large landowners. That access to credit plays a vital role in enabling the adoption of productivity-enhancing innovations is consonant with the literature on the Green Revolution, (Glaeser, 2010).

Our results show that the expansion of irrigation and drainage did not have a direct effect on output. However, we cannot rule out completely the role played by improved irrigation infrastructure because we do not observe investment in private drains, so we cannot assess complementarities between private and public drainage. Further, we find some evidence of a cumulative effect of drainage pipes, two to three years after installation.

The structure of land ownership, specifically the presence of large landowners, contributed to output recovery. Thus, despite institutional innovations designed to give small farmers better access to credit, large landowners benefitted disproportionally from credit availability. This is not a surprising finding: extreme inequality of land holdings had been a central feature of the country’s agricultural system for centuries.

 

References

Eshag, Eprime, and M. A. Kamal. “A Note on the Reform of the Rural Credit System in U.A.R (Egypt).” Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics & Statistics 29, no. 2 (1967): 95–107. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0084.1967.mp29002001.x.

Glaeser, Bernhard. 星星点点灯下载相关百度网盘资源下载_百度云下载:2021-8-25 · 星星点点灯下载相关百度网盘资源下载 百度云下载 按收录时间 按文件大小 按相关性 星星点点的钻石背景_pselement_com.zip百度云下载. Taylor & Francis, 2010.

Goldberg, Ellis. “Historiography of Crisis in the Egyptian Political Economy.” In Middle Eastern Historiographies: Narrating the Twentieth Century, edited by I. Gershoni, Amy Singer, and Hakan Erdem, 183–207. University of Washington Press, 2006.

———. Trade, Reputation and Child Labour in the Twentieth-Century Egypt. Palgrave Macmillan, 2004.

Issawi, Charles. Egypt at Mid-Century. Oxford University Press, 1954.

Owen, Roger. “Agricultural Production in Historical Perspective: A Case Study of the Period 1890-1939.” In Egypt Since the Revolution, edited by P. Vatikiotis, 40–65, 1968.

Radwan, Samir. 百度网盘,让美好永远陪伴:百度网盘为您提供文件的网络备份、同步和分享服务。空间大、速度快、安全稳固,支持教育网加速,支持手机端。现在注册即有机会享受15G的免费存储空间. Ithaca Press, 1974.

Richards, Alan Egypt’s Agricultural Development, 1800-1980: Technical and Social Change. Westview Press, 1982.

 


Ulas Karakoc

ulaslar@gmail.com

 

Laura Panza

lpanza@unimelb.edu.au

 

 

 

 

 

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

By Aaron Graham (Oxford University)

This article will be published in the Economic History Review and is currently available on Early View.

 

lanter专业破解版下载百度云
A Picturesque Tour of the Island of Jamaica, by James Hakewill (1875). Available at Wikimedia Commons.

For a long time the plantation colonies of the Americas were seen as backward and undeveloped, dependent for their wealth on the grinding enslavement of hundreds of thousands of people.  This was only part of the story, albeit a major one. Sugar, coffee, cotton, tobacco and indigo plantations were also some of the largest and most complex economic enterprises of the early industrial revolution, exceeding many textile factories in size and relying upon sophisticated technologies for the processing of raw materials.  My article looks at the patent system of Jamaica and the British Atlantic which supported this system, arguing that it facilitated a process of transatlantic invention, innovation and technological diffusion.

The first key finding concerns the nature of the patent system in Jamaica.  As in British America, patents were granted by colonial legislatures rather than by the Crown, and besides merely registering the proprietary right to an invention they often included further powers, to facilitate the process of licensing and diffusion.  They were therefore more akin to industrial subsidies than modern patents.  The corollary was that inventors had to demonstrate not just novelty but practicality and utility; in 1786, when two inventors competed to patent the same invention, the prize went to the one who provided a successful demonstration (Figure 1).   As a result, the bar was higher, and only about sixty patents were passed in Jamaica between 1664 and 1857, compared to the many thousands in Britain and the United States.

 

32F834948B1F1FF289F5AD7F41CD49BC85993C17.torrent ...:1 天前 · 32F834948B1F1FF289F5AD7F41CD49BC85993C17.torrent百度云网盘下载,资源大小17.45 KB,搜索盘不提供保存服务 ...

Graham1
Source: Bryan Edwards, The History, Civil and Commercial, of the British Colonies of the West Indies (London, 1794).

 

However, the second key finding is that this ‘bar’ was enough to make Jamaica one of the centres of colonial technological innovation before 1770, along with Barbados and South Carolina, which accounted for about two-thirds of the patents passed in that period.  All three were successful plantation colonies, where planters earned large amounts of money and had both the incentive and the means to invest heavily in technological innovations intended to improve efficiency and profits.  Patenting peaked in Jamaica between the 1760s and 1780s, as the island adapted to sudden economic change, as part of a package of measures that included opening up new lands, experimenting with new cane varieties, engaging in closer accounting, importing more slaves and developing new ways of working them harder.

[老友记][10季全][百度云][1994][蓝光高清MKV/1.0G][英语中 ...:2021-6-8 · 注意:若上方有百度云网盘链接,购买前请先点击链接验证是否有效,若失效请勿购买. 本贴资源或提取码需向楼主支付10金币才会显示, VIP会员可免费查看! 购买资源 或 升级VIP 失效反馈 下载教程 更多资源推荐 [星球大战7:原力觉醒][720P+1080P高清 ...

Finally, the colonial patents operated alongside a system of grants, premiums and prizes operated by the Jamaican Assembly, which helped to support innovation by plugging the gaps left by the patent system.  Inventors who felt that their designs were too easily pirated, or that they themselves lacked the capacity to develop them properly, could ask for a grant instead that recompensed them for the costs of invention and made the new technology widely available.  Like the imperial and colonial patents, the grants were part of the strategies used to promote invention.

蓝灯网盘_灯蓝专业版百度云_Lantern百度网盘:2021-3-29 · 蓝灯2.zip百度云资源下载-百度网盘搜索引擎 2021年12月17日 - 蓝灯2.zip,提取密码:,资源类别:文件夹, 浏览次数:2021 次, 文件大小:4G, 由百度云资源分享达人: 百度云搜索 于 2021-12-17 分享到百度网 …

The article therefore argues that Jamaican patents were part of wider transatlantic system that acted to facilitate invention, innovation and technological diffusion in support of the plantation economy and slave society.

 


 

Aaron Graham

aaron.graham@history.ox.ac.uk

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

By Ashish Aggarwal (University of Warwick)

This blog is part of a series of New Researcher blogs.

 

Aggarwal1
Women fetching water in India in the late 19th century. Available at Wikimedia Commons.

A large share of the working population in developing countries is still engaged in agricultural activities. In India, for instance, over 40% of the employed population works in the agricultural sector and nearly three-quarters of the households depend on rural incomes (World Bank[1]). In addition, the agricultural sector in developing countries is plagued with low investments, forcing workers to rely on natural sources for irrigation as opposed to perennial man-made sources. Gadgil and Gadgil (2006) study the agricultural sector in India during 1951-2003 and find that despite a decline in share of agriculture in GDP in India, severe droughts still adversely impact GDP by 2-5%. In such a context, any unanticipated deviation from normal in rainfall is bound to have adverse effects on productivity and consequently, on incomes of these workers. In this paper, I study whether workers adopt migration as a coping strategy in response to income risks arising out of negative shocks to agriculture. And, if local institutions facilitate or hinder the use of this strategy. In a nutshell, the answers are yes and yes.

I study these questions in the context of indentured migration from colonial India to several British colonies. The abolition of slavery in the 1830s led to a demand for new sources of labour to work on plantations in the colonies. Starting with the “great experiment” in Mauritius (Carter, 1993), over a million Indians became indentured migrants with Mauritius, British Guyana, Natal, and Trinidad being the major destinations. The indentured migration from India was a system of voluntary migration, wherein passages were paid-for and migrants earned fixed wages and rations. The exact terms varied across different colonies, but generally the contracts were specified for a period of five years and after ten years of residency in the colony, a paid-for return passage was also available.

比特球云盘 - 让时光传承珍贵:比特球云盘为您提供私人云存储服务,您可众方便的从本地或网络资源链接保存文件到云盘,并随时随地进行预览、下载

 

[1] http://www.worldbank.org/en/news/feature/2012/05/17/india-agriculture-issues-priorities

 

References

Banerjee, Abhijit, and Lakshmi Iyer (2005): “History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India”, American Economic Review, Vol. 95, No. 4, pp. 1190-1213.

Carter, Marina (1993): “The Transition from Slave to Indentured Labour in Mauritius”, Slavery and Abolition, 14:1, pp. 114-130.

Gadgil, Sulochana, and Siddhartha Gadgil (2006): “The Indian Monsoon, GDP and Agriculture”, Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 41, No. 47, 4887-4895.

Persaud, Alexander (2024): “Escaping Local Risk by Entering Indentureship: Evidence from Nineteenth-Century Indian Migration”, Journal of Economic History, Vol. 79, No. 2, pp. 447-476.

 

 

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

蓝 灯下载相关百度网盘资源下载_百度云下载:2021-8-30 · 灯 /百度云资源文件类型:back dir分类:其它由网友: 百合**分享分享的百度云盘资源 上传,累计点击1314次,下载次数为971次 文件类型: dir 大小: 1K 请求数: 2 更新时间: 2021-01-03 11:36:00

This research is due to be presented in the third New Researcher Online Session: ‘Human Capital & Development’.


 

Curtis1
Map of East Canada or Quebec and New Brunswick, by John Tallis c.1850. Available at Wikimedia Commons.

While it plays a key role in theories of the transition to modern economic growth, there are few estimates of the quantity-quality trade-off from before the demographic transition. Using a uniquely suitable new dataset of vital records, I use two instrumental variable (IV) strategies to estimate the trade-off in Quebec between 1620 and 1850. I find that one additional child who survived past age one decreased the literacy rate (proxied by signatures) of their older siblings by 5 percentage points.

The first strategy exploits the fact that twin births, conditional on mother’s age and parity, are a random increase in family size. While twins are often used to identify the trade-off in contemporary studies, sufficiently large and reliable historical datasets containing twins are rare. I compare two families, one whose mother gave birth to twins and one whose mother gave birth to a singleton, both at the same parity and age. I then look at the probability that each older non-twin sibling signed their marriage record.

For the second strategy, I posit that aggregate, province-wide infant mortality rate during the year a younger child was born is exogenous to individual family characteristics. I compare two families, one whose mother gave birth during a year with relatively high infant mortality rate, both at the same parity and age. I then look at older siblings from both families who were born in the same year, controlling for potential time trends in literacy. As the two different IV techniques result in very similar estimates, I argue there is strong evidence of a modest trade-off.

By using two instruments, I am able to rule out one major source of potential bias. In many settings, IV estimates of the trade-off may be biased if parents reallocate resources towards (reinforcement) or away from (compensation) children with higher birth endowments. I show that both twins and children born in high mortality years have, on average, lower literacy rates than their older siblings. As one shock increases and one shock decreases family size, but both result in older siblings having relatively higher human capital, reinforcement or compensation would bias the estimates in different directions. As the estimates are very similar, I conclude there is no evidence that my estimates suffer from this bias.

Is the estimated trade-off economically significant? I compare Quebec to a society with similar culture and institutions: pre-Revolutionary rural France. Between  1628 and 1788, a woman surviving to age 40 in Quebec would expect to have 1.7 additional children surviving past age one compared to her rural French peers. The average literacy rate (again proxied by signatures) in France was about 9.5 percentage points higher than in Quebec. Assuming my estimate of the trade-off is a linear and constant effect (instead of just a local average), reducing family sizes to French levels would have increased literacy by 8.6 percentage points in the next generation, thereby eliminating most of the gap.

响gui下载相关百度网盘资源下载_百度云下载:2021-9-16 · 响gui下载相关百度网盘资源下载 百度云 下载 按收录时间 按文件大小 按相关性 gui.py百度云下载 gui.py /百度云资源文件类型:back no分类:其它由网友:91***09上传,累计点击973次,下载次数 …

 

Data Sources

Henry, Louis, 1978. “Fécondité des mariages dans le quart Sud-Est de la France de 1670 a 1829,” Population (French Edition), 33 (4/5), 855–883.

IMPQ. 2024. Infrastructure intégrée des microdonnées historiques de la population du Québec (XVIIe – XXe siècle) (IMPQ). [Dataset].Centre interuniversitaires d’études              québécoises (CIEQ).

Programme de recherche en démographie historique (PRDH). 2024. Registre de la population du Québec ancien (RPQA). [Dataset]. Département de Démographie, Université de Montréal.

Projet BALSAC. 2024. Le fichier BALSAC. [Dataset]. L’Université du Québec à Chicoutimi.

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

室内灯色完美搭配 灯光打造的实用技巧.doc百度云_百度网盘 ...:2021-5-29 · 室内灯色完美搭配 灯光打造的实用技巧.doc百度云网盘下载,资源大小14.00 KB,搜索盘不提供保存服务,室内灯色完美搭配 灯光打造的实用技巧.doc下载地址将自动跳到百度云网盘下载。

This research is due to be presented in the third New Researcher Online Session: ‘Human Capital & Development’.


 

灯蓝百度云盘
The library of Christ Church, Oxford from Rudolph Ackermann’s History of Oxford (1813). Available at 蓝1灯破解版百度云

 

 

Oxford colleges were among the earliest employers in England to offer organised pension schemes for their workers. These schemes were remarkable for several reasons: they were early, the first was established in 1852; they included domestic servants, rather than white-collar workers; and colleges were unlike typical early adopters of pension schemes, which tended to be large bureaucratic organisations, such as railways or the civil service.

【转】【推荐】蓝灯.zip百度云网盘资源分享下载链接:2021-11-23 · 【转】【推荐】蓝灯.zip 分 享 者:查看列表 分享时间:2021-11-23 11:09:27 文件大小:4.25 MB 文件类型:zip 百度云网盘下载 手机版百度云 提示:通常可众通过《【转】【推荐】蓝灯.zip》的大小来判断文件的质量。EXE后缀的文件请慎重打开,最好先用杀毒软件检测。

Until the Second World War, college servants were often described as a ‘labour aristocracy’, and while there were many successful senior servants, equally there were many casual, part-time and seasonal workers. The experience of these workers provides an unusually detailed look at the precarity of working-class life in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, and the strategies that workers developed to manage uncertainty, especially in old age.

32F834948B1F1FF289F5AD7F41CD49BC85993C17.torrent ...:1 天前 · 32F834948B1F1FF289F5AD7F41CD49BC85993C17.torrent百度云网盘下载,资源大小17.45 KB,搜索盘不提供保存服务 ...

During this period, Oxford was a highly seasonal, low-waged economy. It was hard for many people to find enough work during the year to earn an adequate living, much less save for an old age they usually did not expect to see. Most men and women worked as long as they were capable, often past what we think of as a typical retirement age today.

It’s no surprise then that the protections against illness, disability, old age and death offered by these paternalistic employers encouraged a highly competitive labour market for college work, and the promise of an ex gratia, or traditional non-contributory pension, was one of the most attractive features of college employment.

For centuries, colleges awarded these traditional pensions to workers. Rights to these pensions, which usually replaced about a quarter to a third of a worker’s total earnings, were insecure and awards were made entirely at the discretion of the college.

In 1852, the first retirement savings scheme for Oxford college servants was created at Balliol College. By the 1920s, traditional non-contributory pensions had been replaced by contributory schemes at most Oxford colleges, shifting the risk of old age from employers to employees. Even though making contributions often meant a decrease in take-home pay, servants always preferred a guaranteed pension entitlement over traditional non-contributory pensions.

The earliest savings schemes mandated the purchase of life insurance policies. These were intended not only to protect a servant’s dependent family members, but also to limit the college’s financial liability in the event of a servant’s death. Servants were similarly risk-averse and often purchased multiple policies when they could afford to; many joined friendly societies and purchased insurance privately, in addition to employer-directed schemes.

The popularity of these schemes among Oxford colleges mirrors the growth of the insurance industry and the development of actuarial science during this period. By the 1870s, nearly all schemes included annuities or endowment assurance policies, which provided a guaranteed income for servants, usually at age 60-65, and facilitated the introduction of mandatory retirement ages for these workers.

Traditional paternalism remained influential throughout the period. Colleges insisted on controlling insurance policies, naming themselves as beneficiaries and directing the proceeds. Women, who were more likely to be in low-waged seasonal work, were nearly always excluded from these schemes and had to depend on ex gratia pension awards much longer than their male colleagues.

These early pension schemes offered no protection against inflation and colleges were usually slow to increase pension awards in response to rising prices. By the end of the Great War, dissatisfaction with inadequate pensions was one of several factors that pushed college servants to form a trade union in 1919.

 

每天试用一小时vpvp-雷霆加器速

By Laura Wurm (Queen’s University Belfast)

This blog is part of a series of New Researcher blogs.

 

101123-A-0193C-001
Farmland in Dalat, Vietnam. Available at 蓝·灯下载

 

Ever since the emergence of futures markets and speculation, the effects of futures trading on spot price volatility have been subject to intense debate. While the populist discourse affirms the adverse and price-disturbing consequences of futures trading, the work of scholars stresses the risk allocation and information transmission function of futures towards spot markets, essential for pricing cash transactions. My research tests whether these volatility-lowering effects of futures trading towards the cash market hold true by assuming the opposite: what happens if futures trading no longer exists?

To do so, I go back to the early 20th century, when futures trading in the Viennese grain market was, unlike at other trade locations at the time, such as Germany, England, or Texas, banned permanently. The 1903 parliament-enforced prohibition of futures trading was the consequence of an aversion against speculators, who were blamed for “never having held actual grain in their hands”. Putting an end to the vibrant futures market of the Agricultural Products Exchange, the city’s gathering place for farmers, millers, large-scale customers, and speculators, was thought to be the last resort to curb undue speculation. Up to the present day, futures trading has not been resumed. The uniqueness of this ban makes it an ideally suited natural experiment to test the effects of futures trading and its abolishment on spot price volatility. Prices from the Budapest Stock and Commodity Exchange, which was not affected by the ban, are used as a synthetic control. The Budapest market, as part of the Austro-Hungarian Empire, operated under similar legal-economic and geographic conditions, and was, in addition to Vienna, the only Austro-Hungarian market offering a trade in futures. This makes Budapest an ideally suited control.

百度云搜索,百度云盘资源下载,百度网盘搜索 - 搜百度盘:搜百度盘(SoBaiduPan.com) 是基于百度云搜索,最大的百度云盘资源搜索中心,千万级大数据量,让您一网打尽所有的百度网盘资源. 网盘搜索 站长推荐:2021年新一伕百度网盘等云盘免费资源搜索引擎系 …

 

 


Laura Wurm

lwurm01@qub.ac.uk

 

Food Security, Trade and Violence: From the First to the Second Globalization in Colombia 1916-2016 (NR Online Session 2)

By Alexander Urrego-Mesa (Universitat de Barcelona)

This research is due to be presented in the second Lantern官方网站: ‘Industry, Trade & Technology’


 

 

With world population forecasted at 9 billion by 2050, and climate change hazards, maintaining the capacity to provide food becomes paramount for national governments, especially in developing countries. After the Second War World and the Oil Crises, food aid and trade liberalisation helped to distribute food from surplus countries to those in deficit. (Dithmer, J., & Abdulai, A. 2017).

Nonetheless, some scholars suggest that trade liberalization and agro-export specialization threaten domestic food security in developing countries (Kumar Sharma, 2016), for the following reasons: it promotes increasing dependence on food exporters, increases vulnerability when confronting volatile agrarian prices, and jeopardizes domestic production by promoting agro-exports. Moreover, the rise of agrarian trade contributes to rising consumption of fossil-fuel-based inputs like nutrients, fuel, machinery, and intensifies the use of natural resources, thereby contributing to soil erosion, greenhouse gas emissions and the loss of biodiversity. (D’Odorico et al., 2014).

Nonetheless, little is known about how the relationship between trade, food availability, and food production has evolved. This research contributes to the food security debate at the national level by introducing a historic long-rung approach and comparing the two main periods of food trade, the First and the Second Globalization in a developing context.

 

Figure 1. Food trade balance (1916-2016)

蓝1灯破解版百度云
Note: Positive values indicate imports, negative values refer to exports, and the solid black line indicates net imports.

 

I analyse the long-run trend of food security in Colombia, a relevant developing country and one of the most biodiverse countries on the planet. I build on data from the early 20th century to the present, on agrarian trade, food availability, and self-sufficiency (SS) -understood as the capacity of the agrarian system to meet domestic demand.

黑底彩花蓝底白花陶釉装饰碗.zip百度云_百度网盘下载 - 搜索盘:1 天前 · 黑底彩花蓝底白花陶釉装饰碗.zip为搜索盘收集整理于百度云网盘资源,搜索盘不提供保存服务,下载地址跳到百度云盘下载,文件的安全性和完整性请您自行判断。如果感觉本站提供的服务对于您有帮助,请按 Ctrl+D 收藏本网站,感谢您对本站的支持。

Although the import of wheat and rice served to face food shortages at the end of the 1920s and in the early 1950s, importing maize has become the rule to guarantee the availability of food during the Second Globalization. This increase in imports allowed the gains in per capita consumption but eroded the SS capacity of the domestic agrarian system to provide food. On the other side, the long-rung agro-export specialisation led to increasing the capacity to supply international markets with tropical products (Figure 2).

 

Figure 2. Self-sufficiency index by groups of products

latern专业破解版安卓最新版
Note: A result greater than one indicates the agrarian system is a domestic and international supplier of food, whereas a value less than one means the domestic consumption relies on imports.

 

Finally, I explore the role of international agrarian prices and political violence in shaping tropical specialisation and food dependence in the 1980s.  I find a negative relationship (-0.75) between the prices of cereals relative to tropical products (coffee, banana, sugarcane, and oil palm), and the trade balance. Regarding internal factors,  the self-sufficiency index and political violence are negatively correlated for cereals and pulses, and positively correlated for sugar cane.

Violence in Colombia contributes to land grabbing to develop agribusiness projects. It leads to the displacement of the labour force in the countryside. Thus, political violence is responsible for growing demand for food in cities and, at the same time, for the lack of capacity to provide it from the agrarian sector. If the evolution of relative prices is the incentive to deepen food dependence and tropical specialisation, violence is the means to achieve this.

 

 

References

Dithmer, J., & Abdulai, A. (2017). Does trade openness contribute to food security? A dynamic panel analysis. Food Policy, 69, 218-230.

D’Odorico, P., Carr, J. A., Laio, F., Ridolfi, L., & Vandoni, S. (2014). Feeding humanity through global food trade. Earth’s Future, 2(9), 458-469.

Kumar Sharma, Sachin (2016). The WTO and Food Security. Implications for Developing Countries. Singapore. Springer.

 


蓝1灯破解版百度云

alex.urrego.mesa@ub.edu

@AlexUrrego3

 

Why is Switzerland so rich? The role of early electricity adoption (NR Online Session 2)

by Björn Brey (University of Nottingham)

This research is due to be presented in the second New Researcher Online Session: ‘Industry, Trade & Technology’


 

After its first commercial usage in 1879, Switzerland experienced a drastic increase in electricity production reflected in it having the highest per capita production in the world by 1900. During the same time period, Swiss GDP growth accelerated considerably compared with other industrialising countries (see Figure 1).

 

Figure 1: Real GDP per capita in 1990US$ across leading industrial countries from 1850-1970. 1879 reflects the first commercial usage of electricity in Switzerland.

Bjoern1
Source: Maddison Project Database, version 2018

 

求蓝灯的百度云资源,感谢! - Sogou:2021-10-15 · 有的呢 链接:https://pan.baidu.com/s/1mvfftooscvmp6svpgrgsjg 密码:8y75 链接一天内有效,请速度保存! 满意请采纳,谢谢! 失效有疑问私 ...

My research, to be presented at the annual conference of the Economic History Society in Oxford in April 2024, answers these questions by analysing the impact of the early adoption of electricity across Switzerland on economic development through exploiting the quasi-random potential to generate electricity from waterpower.

My study finds that the adoption of electricity between 1880 and 1900 considerably increased the contemporaneous manufacturing employment share. This initial effect persists up to today with the average district observing a 1.5% higher manufacturing employment share in 2011 due to the adoption of electricity up to 1900.

This effect of early electricity adoption on employment shares in agriculture, manufacturing and services in the long run is depicted in Figure 2. Notably, the growth in manufacturing employment observed can be attributed in particular to chemical industries, which relied on access to electricity for newly developed production processes.

This effect on economic development is also observable in incomes across districts with a one standard deviation higher exposure to electricity between 1880 and 1900 leading to a 1949 Swiss Francs ($2004) higher yearly median income in 2010.

 

Figure 2: Estimated IV-coefficients on the effect of a one horsepower increase in electricity production 1880-1900 on the change in the employment share across sectors from 1880 to the respective year as well as the pre-trend period 1860-1880.

Bjoern2

 

For the analysis, I newly digitised historic information on electricity production by waterpower plants across the whole of Switzerland and construct geocoded data on all potential waterpower plants that could be built as estimated by a plan of Swiss government engineers at the time.

These data are illustrated in Figure 3. Combining this information allows me to use the potential to produce electricity across districts to infer the causal impact of electricity adoption on economic development across Switzerland.

 

Figure 3: The map shows the exploited and potential waterpower in Switzerland in 1914. Blue-dots represent exploited waterpower, red-dots represent potential waterpower, both of existing natural sources and grey-dots represent existing and potential water-power plants that requires the building of an embankment dam. The sites are coded into 5 categories: 20-99HP, 100-999HP, 1000-4999HP, 5000-9999HP and above 10000HP.

Bjoern3

 

These results provide new insight into how early access to electricity at the end of the nineteenth century helps to explain differences in economic development today. Interestingly, the long-run effect of electricity appears not to be explained by persistent differences in electricity consumption across Switzerland after the roll-out of the electricity grid in the 1920s, but rather due to increased investment into education that was complementary to the newly industries that had newly developed.

 


 

 

 

 

Lantern官方网站

By Mostafa Abdelaal (University of Cambridge)

This research is due to be presented in the second New Researcher Online Session: ‘Industry, Trade & Technology’


 

Northern Rhodesia joined Southern Rhodesia and Nyasaland to form the Central African Federation (CAF), which lasted from 1953 to 1963 (Figure 1). During this period, two contrasting images were formed about the Federation’s economic prospects.   The first depicts the exploitation of the revenue surpluses of Northern Rhodesia in favour of Southern Rhodesia, (Figure 2). The second typifies Kitwe, one of the main mining-town in the Copperbelt in Northern Rhodesia, as the most rapidly developed town in terms of industrial and commercial sectors (Figure 3). My research examines whether the Federation stimulated or undermined manufacturing growth.

 

Figure 1: Map of the Central African Federation, 1953-1963

灯蓝百度云盘
Source:  Papers relating to Central African Federation [1952-1958], British Library, EAP121/1/3/16, http://eap.bl.uk/archive-file/EAP121-1-3-16

响gui下载相关百度网盘资源下载_百度云下载:2021-9-16 · 响gui下载相关百度网盘资源下载 百度云 下载 按收录时间 按文件大小 按相关性 gui.py百度云下载 gui.py /百度云资源文件类型:back no分类:其它由网友:91***09上传,累计点击973次,下载次数 …

 

Figure 2.  Cartoon published by Central African Post mirroring one of the readers’ views on the Federation

Mostafa2
Source: Papers relating to Central African Federation [1952-1958], British Library, EAP121/1/3/16, http://eap.bl.uk/archive-file/EAP121-1-3-16

Figure 3: Kitwe: A model of a mining town in the Copperbelt

Mostafa3
Source: NZA, ZIMCO,  1/1/3/ 10, From Mr Gresh the Managing Director of the Northern Rhodesia Industrial Development Corporation Ltd., to the Managing Director of Marcheurop, Brussels, 5th July 1962.

 

My research offers new insights into the rapid growth of the market in Northern Rhodesia. Specifically, to what extent did local industry respond to the mining-led economic expansion in Northern Rhodesia.  The first census of industrial production occurred in 1947, which provides a benchmark against which to measure growth rates before and during the Federal tariff system. Industrial production in Northern and Southern Rhodesia grew from 3.3 percent to 6 percent, and from 12 percent to 16.3 percent, respectively, between 1954 and 1963.  The net value added of manufacturing in Northern Rhodesia grew from less than £1 million in 1947 to £6.40 million in 1955, then it reached £12.68 million in 1963. Southern Rhodesia witnessed a significant increase in the net value added of manufacturing, from £20 million in 1953 to £50.2 million in 1963.

The composition of manufacturing output before and during the Federation reveals that rapid growth in Northern Rhodesia’s production of food, drinks, textiles, and chemicals — which constituted the majority of domestically manufactured goods (Table 2).

Table 2

Net value added of manufacturing output in Northern Rhodesia (£ million, nominal)

Sector/Year 1947 1955 1963
Food, drink and tobacco 0.20 1.56 5.13
Textiles, clothing, footwear 0.019 0.14 0.43
Metal engineering and repairs 0.082 a 1.58
Lantern官方网站 a a 1.83
Wood industries 蓝1灯破解版百度云 0.46b 0.85
Building materials 0.010 c c
Transport equipment a 1.36 1.43
Printing and publishing 0.11 0.36 0.64
latern专业破解版安卓最新版 0.071 2.53 0.80
Total 0.710 6.40 12.68
a) Included in ‘others’

b) excluding furniture

比特球云盘 - 让时光传承珍贵:比特球云盘为您提供私人云存储服务,您可众方便的从本地或网络资源链接保存文件到云盘,并随时随地进行预览、下载

d) includes manufacture of tobacco, made-up textiles other than apparel, furniture, retreading of tyres, chemicals, non-metallic minerals, metal industries other than transport equipment and other, not elsewhere specified (n.e.s.) in 1955, leather and rubber products, chemicals, pottery and other (n.e.s.) in 1963.

Sources: TNA CO 798/24, Blue Books of Statistics, 1947; NAZ, Monthly Digest of Statistics, Central Statistics Office, Lusaka, December 1955, 1964; Young (1973).

 

My research suggests a more nuanced interpretation is required of the importance of Northern Rhodesia to the South. The Federation curbed Northern Rhodesia’s development of specific industries that existed in Southern Rhodesia, especially steel and textiles, thereby disrupting the optimum allocation resources to industrial production in the South.

However, Northern Rhodesia’s net value added of manufacturing output benefited from the application of Federal tariffs in certain consumer industries that grew rapidly, such as processed foods and drinks. Consequently, the Federation was beneficial to the growth of manufacturing in Northern Rhodesia (Zambia).

 


 

Mostafa Abdelaal

ma710@cam.ac.uk